Cambridge A2 Level Economics 9708 (eBook)
228 Seiten
epubli (Verlag)
978-3-8187-4567-7 (ISBN)
I am bestselling author. Data scientist. Cambridge Alumnus. I have proven technical skills (MBA, ACCA (Knowledge Level- FTMS college Malaysia), BBA, several Google certifications such as Google Data Analytics Specialization, Google Digital Marketing & E-commerce Specialization, and Google Project Management Specialization) to deliver insightful books with ten years of business experience. I have written and published 650+ titles. ORCID: https://orcid.org/0009-0004-8629-830X Azhar.sario@hotmail.co.uk
I am bestselling author. Data scientist. Cambridge Alumnus. I have proven technical skills (MBA, ACCA (Knowledge Level- FTMS college Malaysia), BBA, several Google certifications such as Google Data Analytics Specialization, Google Digital Marketing & E-commerce Specialization, and Google Project Management Specialization) to deliver insightful books with ten years of business experience. I have written and published 650+ titles. ORCID: https://orcid.org/0009-0004-8629-830X Azhar.sario@hotmail.co.uk
Types of cost, revenue and profit, short-run and long-run production
Part 1: Short-Run Production Function
Fixed and Variable Factors of Production
In the short run, production involves both fixed and variable factors. Fixed factors are those that cannot be easily changed in the short term. These include assets like machinery, buildings, and land. Regardless of the level of production, these factors remain constant. Variable factors, on the other hand, can be adjusted based on the production volume. These typically include labor, raw materials, and energy consumption.
Total Product, Average Product, and Marginal Product
Total Product (TP) is the total output produced by a firm using given quantities of fixed and variable factors. It's calculated by simply summing up all the units of product produced.
Average Product (AP) is the output produced per unit of variable factor employed. It's calculated by dividing the total product by the number of units of the variable factor used (AP = TP / Quantity of Variable Factor).
Marginal Product (MP) refers to the additional output produced by adding one more unit of a variable factor. It's calculated by the change in total product resulting from a one-unit change in the variable factor (MP = ÄTP / ÄVariable Factor).
Law of Diminishing Returns (Law of Variable Proportions)
The law of diminishing returns states that as additional units of a variable factor are added to a fixed factor, beyond a certain point, the marginal product of the variable factor will begin to decrease. Initially, adding more labor or raw materials might increase output more efficiently, but after reaching optimal capacity, further additions produce less and less extra output.
Example: Imagine a café that has only one coffee machine (a fixed factor). As the café hires more baristas (variable factor), the total product (cups of coffee made per day) increases. Initially, the average and marginal products rise because more hands make light work. However, after a certain point, adding more baristas leads to overcrowding and inefficiencies, causing the marginal product to fall.
Part 2: Short-Run Cost Function
Fixed Costs (FC) and Variable Costs (VC)
Fixed Costs (FC) are costs include rent, salaries of permanent staff, and insurance. Regardless of how much is produced, these costs remain constant.
Variable Costs (VC) change with the level of production. These include costs for raw materials, energy consumption, and wages of temporary staff.
Total, Average, and Marginal Costs
Total Cost (TC) is the sum of total fixed costs and total variable costs (TC = TFC + TVC).
Average Total Cost (ATC) is the total cost per unit of output, also known as unit cost (ATC = TC / Quantity of Output).
Average Fixed Cost (AFC) is the fixed cost per unit of output (AFC = TFC / Quantity of Output).
Average Variable Cost (AVC) is the variable cost per unit of output (AVC = TVC / Quantity of Output).
Marginal Cost (MC). It's calculated by the change in total cost resulting from a one-unit change in output (MC = ÄTC / ÄQuantity of Output).
Shape of Short-Run Average and Marginal Cost Curves
The average cost (AC) curve typically shows a U-shape in the short run. Initially, as output increases, AC decreases due to spreading the fixed costs over more units and utilizing variable factors more efficiently. However, after reaching a certain level of production, AC starts to increase because of the law of diminishing returns affecting variable costs.
The marginal cost (MC) curve usually first declines as output increases, reflecting efficiencies in adding more production up to a point. Beyond this point, MC increases as the law of diminishing returns kicks in. MC intersects the ATC at its lowest point, highlighting the most efficient scale of production in the short run.
Example: Consider a bakery producing cakes. The rent for the shop (a fixed cost) remains constant whether the bakery makes 10 or 100 cakes a day. The cost of flour and eggs (variable costs) increases as more cakes are baked. Initially, as production increases, spreading the fixed rent over more cakes lowers the average cost. However, as production continues to increase, the bakery runs into capacity issues—ovens can only bake so many cakes at once, leading to overtime wages and higher variable costs per cake. Thus, the MC and AC curves initially fall but then rise as production scales up.
1. Long-Run Production Function
In economics, understanding the long-run production function is crucial for grasping how output responds to changes in inputs over time when there are no fixed factors of production. The long-run is a period wherein all inputs or factors of production, including capital, labor, and technology, can be varied. No factor is fixed; firms can adjust all their resources to optimize production.
Returns to Scale
The concept of returns to scale describes how the quantity of output changes as the scale of all inputs changes. In the long run, there are three possibilities:
Increasing Returns to Scale (Economies of Scale): If output increases by a larger proportion than the increase in inputs, we say there are increasing returns to scale. For example, doubling the inputs results in more than doubling the output. This often happens due to factors like specialization, better use of technology, and efficiencies of large-scale production.
Constant Returns to Scale: Here, output changes in the same proportion as the inputs. Doubling all inputs leads to doubling the output. This scenario suggests that the firm is operating efficiently, and scaling up production does not lead to efficiency gains or losses.
Decreasing Returns to Scale (Diseconomies of Scale): This occurs when the output increases by a smaller proportion than the increase in inputs. For instance, if doubling the inputs results in less than doubling the output, the firm faces diseconomies of scale, possibly due to challenges in managing a larger operation, communication issues, or logistical constraints.
2. Long-Run Cost Function
The long-run cost function provides insight into how the cost of production changes as the scale of operation changes, with all factors of production being variable.
Shape of the Long-Run Average Cost Curve
The long-run average cost (LRAC) curve is typically U-shaped due to economies and diseconomies of scale. Initially, as a firm increases its scale of production, it benefits from lower average costs due to economies of scale. This is the downward-sloping part of the U-shaped LRAC curve. However, beyond a certain point, the firm may experience diseconomies of scale, where further increases in scale lead to higher average costs, represented by the upward-sloping part of the curve.
Minimum Efficient Scale
Minimum Efficient Scale (MES) is the point on the LRAC curve where a firm achieves the lowest possible average cost of production, taking full advantage of economies of scale. Beyond this point, the firm starts to face diseconomies of scale. MES is crucial for understanding the competitive dynamics within an industry. Industries with a high MES tend to have fewer competitors due to the high initial costs of achieving efficient production scales.
3. Relationship Between Economies of Scale and Decreasing Average Costs
Economies of scale play a pivotal role in determining a firm's cost structure and competitive position. As a firm expands its production and lowers its average costs, it can gain a competitive edge by offering lower prices or achieving higher margins. The relationship between economies of scale and decreasing average costs is foundational to strategic decision-making in business. Firms strive to operate at a scale where they can minimize average costs, thus maximizing their efficiency and profitability.
Economies of scale lead to decreasing average costs through several mechanisms:
Technical Economies: Larger firms can invest in more efficient technology that lowers the cost per unit of production.
Managerial Economies: As firms grow, they can employ specialized managers for different functions, improving efficiency and lowering costs.
Financial Economies: Larger firms often have better access to finance at lower interest rates.
Marketing Economies: Larger production volumes allow firms to spread their fixed marketing costs over a larger output, reducing the average cost.
1. Internal and External Economies of Scale
Internal Economies of Scale refer to the cost-saving advantages that a company experiences as it increases production. These benefits are internal to the firm and often include:
Technical Economies: Buying in bulk or using more efficient technology can lower the average cost.
Managerial Economies: Specializing management roles can improve efficiency and reduce costs.
Financial Economies: Larger firms often get loans at lower interest rates.
Marketing Economies: Spreading fixed marketing costs over a larger output.
Network Economies: As a firm grows, it might benefit from a larger network, enhancing its value.
Example: A smartphone manufacturer might reduce costs per unit by investing in advanced robotics for assembly lines, a clear case of technical economies of scale.
External Economies of Scale occur outside of a...
Erscheint lt. Verlag | 13.12.2024 |
---|---|
Verlagsort | Berlin |
Sprache | englisch |
Themenwelt | Schulbuch / Wörterbuch |
Sozialwissenschaften ► Pädagogik ► Erwachsenenbildung | |
Schlagworte | A2 Economics textbook • Cambridge 9708 economics A levels • cambridge economics Exam Preparation • cambridge economics Study Guide • cambridge economics Textbook • Macroeconomics • Microeconomics |
ISBN-10 | 3-8187-4567-6 / 3818745676 |
ISBN-13 | 978-3-8187-4567-7 / 9783818745677 |
Informationen gemäß Produktsicherheitsverordnung (GPSR) | |
Haben Sie eine Frage zum Produkt? |
Größe: 489 KB
Digital Rights Management: ohne DRM
Dieses eBook enthält kein DRM oder Kopierschutz. Eine Weitergabe an Dritte ist jedoch rechtlich nicht zulässig, weil Sie beim Kauf nur die Rechte an der persönlichen Nutzung erwerben.
Dateiformat: EPUB (Electronic Publication)
EPUB ist ein offener Standard für eBooks und eignet sich besonders zur Darstellung von Belletristik und Sachbüchern. Der Fließtext wird dynamisch an die Display- und Schriftgröße angepasst. Auch für mobile Lesegeräte ist EPUB daher gut geeignet.
Systemvoraussetzungen:
PC/Mac: Mit einem PC oder Mac können Sie dieses eBook lesen. Sie benötigen dafür die kostenlose Software Adobe Digital Editions.
eReader: Dieses eBook kann mit (fast) allen eBook-Readern gelesen werden. Mit dem amazon-Kindle ist es aber nicht kompatibel.
Smartphone/Tablet: Egal ob Apple oder Android, dieses eBook können Sie lesen. Sie benötigen dafür eine kostenlose App.
Geräteliste und zusätzliche Hinweise
Buying eBooks from abroad
For tax law reasons we can sell eBooks just within Germany and Switzerland. Regrettably we cannot fulfill eBook-orders from other countries.
aus dem Bereich