The Limits of Choice (eBook)

Saving Decisions and Basic Needs in Developed Countries
eBook Download: PDF
2013 | 1. Auflage
327 Seiten
Campus Verlag
978-3-593-42111-7 (ISBN)

Lese- und Medienproben

The Limits of Choice -  Sahra Wagenknecht
Systemvoraussetzungen
34,99 inkl. MwSt
  • Download sofort lieferbar
  • Zahlungsarten anzeigen
Wann und warum sparen private Haushalte? Sahra Wagenknecht untersucht in ihrer Dissertation den Zusammenhang von Sparentscheidungen und Grundbedürfnissen in Deutschland und den USA von den 1950er-Jahren bis heute. Ihre zentrale Hypothese lautet, dass der Einkommensanteil der Ausgaben zur Befriedigung von Grundbedürfnissen die entscheidende Erklärungsvariable des individuellen Sparverhaltens darstellt. In Abgrenzung zur Lebenszyklus- bzw. Permanenten Einkommenshypothese (LCPIH) kann Wagenknecht zeigen, dass die individuelle Sparquote entscheidend vom langfristigen Einkommen abhängt. Die Arbeit weist für einen Zeitraum von über 50 Jahren nach, dass sich auch auf volkswirtschaftlicher Ebene die Veränderung der privaten Sparquote durch den 'necessity share' erklären lässt. Das vorgelegte Modell liefert zudem eine Erklärung, weshalb die private Sparquote bei steigender Einkommensungleichheit in Volkswirtschaften mit dereguliertem Kreditmarkt sinkt, während sie bei restriktiven Kreditmärkten steigt.

Sahra Wagenknecht ist promovierte Volkswirtin, Publizistin und Politikerin, seit Oktober 2015 Vorsitzende der Linksfraktion im Deutschen Bundestag. Von 2010 bis 2014 war sie Stellvertretende Parteivorsitzende, von 2004 bis 2009 Abgeordnete im Europäischen Parlament.

Sahra Wagenknecht ist promovierte Volkswirtin, Publizistin und Politikerin, seit Oktober 2015 Vorsitzende der Linksfraktion im Deutschen Bundestag. Von 2010 bis 2014 war sie Stellvertretende Parteivorsitzende, von 2004 bis 2009 Abgeordnete im Europäischen Parlament.

Contents 6
List of Figures 12
List of Variables and Abbreviations 14
Introduction 20
Chapter 1. Stylised Facts of Saving 32
Paragraph 1.1 Data Sets and Statistical Issues 34
1.1.1 Various Saving Aggregates and Their Relationship 34
1.1.2 Macroeconomic Data Sources for the U.S. and Germany 35
1.1.3 Measurement Problems—Saving Offshore or Saving Out of Realised Capital Gains 37
1.1.4 Statistical Revisions 38
1.1.5 Microeconomic Data Sources for the U.S. and Germany 39
Paragraph 1.2 The Historic Path of Saving 41
1.2.1 General Trends in the OECD 41
1.2.2 Saving in the U.S. and its Various Components 41
1.2.3 Saving in Germany and its Various Components 45
Paragraph 1.3 Stylised Facts at the Macroeconomic Level 48
1.3.1 Real Income 48
1.3.2 Growth 50
1.3.3 Real Interest Rates 52
1.3.4 Inflation 53
1.3.5 Unemployment and Social Security Standards 55
1.3.6 Demographics 56
1.3.7 Inequality 56
1.3.8 Institutional Environment 59
1.3.9 Persistency 60
Paragraph 1.4 Stylised Facts at the Microeconomic Level 61
1.4.1 Macroeconomic Facts and Microeconomic Distributions 61
1.4.2 Saving Rates in Cross-Section 62
1.4.3 Current Income, Real and Relative 65
1.4.4 Permanent Income 73
1.4.5 The Distribution of Financial Wealth 75
1.4.6 Growth, Income Fluctuations and the Role of Expectations 80
1.4.7 Uncertainty and Precautionary Saving 84
1.4.8 Life-Cycle Patterns of Saving 86
1.4.9 Saving Motives 88
Paragraph 1.5 Summary: Stylised Facts of Saving 90
Chapter 2. Do Standard Models of Saving Match the Facts? 92
Paragraph 2.1 The Standard LCPIH 94
2.1.1 Basic Ideas of the Standard Approach 94
2.1.2 The Modigliani-Diagram 95
2.1.3 The Perfect Foresight Model in Discrete Time 98
2.1.4 The Perfect Foresight Model in Continuous Time 102
2.1.5 The Certainty Equivalent Model 105
Paragraph 2.2 The Empirical Failure of the Standard Models 109
2.2.1 Excess Sensitivity and Excess Smoothness—Ambiguous Results 109
2.2.2 MPC and Income Growth—Wrong Predictions 110
2.2.3 Incapability to Explain Saving Rate Differentials 111
Paragraph 2.3 Refinements: Allowing for Precautionary Saving, Liquidity Constraints and Habit Formation 113
2.3.1 Convex Marginal Utility and the Precautionary Motive 113
2.3.2 The Technique of Stochastic Dynamic Programming 114
2.3.3 The Buffer-Stock Model 117
2.3.4 Liquidity Constrained Consumers 121
2.3.5 Models Including Habit Formation 122
Paragraph 2.4 Do the Elaborated Models Perform Better? 126
2.4.1 Gain in Realism at the Cost of Predictive Power 126
2.4.2 Remaining Deficiencies 127
Paragraph 2.5 The Optimal Consumption Path—General Remarks 129
2.5.1 Hidden Assumptions and Fundamental Flaws 129
2.5.2 Arguments of the Utility Function—Wealth as an End in Itself 130
2.5.3 A Realistic Time-Horizon 132
2.5.4 The Representative Consumer 133
2.5.5 Per-period Consumption as a Single Entity 139
2.5.6 The Elasticity of Intertemporal Substitution 142
2.5.7 The Optimising Procedure—Benefits and Costs 146
Chapter 3. A New Approach to Saving Behaviour 150
Paragraph 3.1 Basic Needs and Saving 152
3.1.1 The Relative-Income Hypothesis 152
3.1.2 Subsistence Consumption in Developing Countries 153
3.1.3 Necessities in Developed Countries 157
Paragraph 3.2 Basic Needs in Standard Models 160
3.2.1 Introducing Good-specific Subsistence Points into a Standard Dixit-Stiglitz framework 160
3.2.2 Intertemporal Optimisation with Moving Subsistence Consumption 172
Paragraph 3.3 Modelling Saving Decisions by a Simple Rule of Thumb 179
3.3.1 The Necessity Share in Outlay and in Income 181
3.3.2 Determinants of Saving under the Proposed Rule of Thumb 182
3.3.3 The Aggregated Saving Rate under the Given Rule of Thumb 185
3.3.4 Factors Influencing the Propensity to Save and to Dissave 192
3.3.5 Summary: Model Predictions 193
Chapter 4. The Patterns of Consumption Shares 196
Paragraph 4.1 How to Identify Basic Needs? 198
4.1.1 Two Approaches to the Historic Path of the Necessity Share 198
4.1.2 Basic Expenditure Groups versus Luxury Spending 201
Paragraph 4.2 Consumption Patterns at the Macroeconomic Level 204
4.2.1 Consumption Shares and Sectoral Prices in Germany 204
4.2.2 Consumption Shares and Sectoral Prices in the U.S. 207
Paragraph 4.3 Consumption Patterns at the Microeconomic Level 211
4.3.1 Methodological Notes 211
4.3.2 Food 212
4.3.3 Shelter 214
4.3.4 Clothing 215
4.3.5 Transportation 216
4.3.6 Communication 218
4.3.7 Furniture and Household Devices 218
4.3.8 Health Care 219
4.3.9 Entertainment and Recreation 220
4.3.10 Education 220
4.3.11 Restaurants and Hotels 221
Paragraph 4.4 Summary: The Historic Path of the Necessity Share 222
4.4.1 What Belongs in the Necessity Basket? 222
4.4.2 First Approach to the Necessity Share 223
4.4.3 Second Approach to the Necessity Share 225
4.4.4 The Individual Necessity Share 230
Chapter 5. Does Our Model Match the Facts? 234
Paragraph 5.1 Model Predictions and the Stylised Facts of Saving 236
Paragraph 5.2 Model Predictions and Empirical Evidence at the Microeconomic Level 239
5.2.1 The Necessity Share and German Saving Rates 239
5.2.2 Reproducing U.S. Saving Rates of the Mid-20th Century 251
Paragraph 5.3 Model Predictions and Empirical Evidence at the Macroeconomic Level 257
5.3.1 Preliminary Notes 257
5.3.2 Saving Rate and Basic Needs in Germany 258
5.3.3 Saving Rate and Basic Needs in the U.S. 263
5.3.4 Is Our Model Able to Reproduce the Historic Path? 267
Summary 304
References 310

Introduction

Despite a large amount of detailed economic research studying consump-tion and saving behaviour in several countries, utilizing high-level mathe-matics as well as highly powerful statistical software, the performance of theories attempting to explain the empirical facts still seems to be unsatis-factory. In fact, there is a clear gap between empirically oriented papers about saving on the one hand, and on the other one that part of the literature, which is primarily concerned with estimating the parameters for models of intertemporal utility maximisation that are assumed to guide consumer behaviour. While the issues raised by the latter interest only those believing in the respective models, publications with an empirical focus often reveal interesting relationships of undeniable meaning. Ultimately, these studies mostly note a conflict between their findings and the predictions of mainstream theories.

However, saving is certainly one of the crucial economic variables. Since private-household saving usually accounts for the major part of na-tional saving, it is desirable indeed to clarify what drives an ordinary con-sumer to save or consume his wealth, and to understand how such deci-sions are affected by changes in the economic environment or by politically controlled parameters.

For decades, the Life Cycle/Permanent Income Hypothesis (LCPIH), originally formulated by Friedman (1957) and Modigliani & Brumberg (1954), subsequently highly formalised by making use of dynamic pro-gramming techniques and optimal control theory, has been the central paradigm in economics for studying consumption and saving behaviour. The LCPIH assumes households optimise the utility of consumption in-tertemporally, subject to permanent income or life-time wealth. In this approach, saving is merely a by-product of the optimal consumption path. The exclusive purpose of saving is future consumption since the only trade-off a consumer faces is the trade-off between current and future spending.

The mainstream models are based on the assumption of homothetic preferences and additive intertemporal utility. Preferences are assumed not to be interdependent. The optimal intertemporal consumption path is presumed to be governed by the relationship between the real interest rate, rewarding the accumulation of financial wealth, and a discount factor measuring the degree at which households depreciate future consumption compared to immediate pleasure.

The central prediction of these models under perfect foresight or cer-tainty-equivalent conditions states that consumption does not respond to current changes in income if these have been expected in advance. The effect of an unexpected income shock depends on its impact on perma-nent income. If the income shock is considered to be transitory, consumption remains stable; a transitory income gain will be mainly saved, while a transitory loss will be balanced by dissaving. Only if the consumer expects the shock to be persistent, is consumption adjusted upwards or downwards. The marginal propensity to consume (MPC) out of an increase in current income is consistently assumed to be exactly the same as the MPC out of an increase of equal present value in expected future income.

Vital issues of research within such an approach are to distinguish transitory and permanent income shocks as well as expected and unexpected events. A major focus within empirical work is on estimating the intertemporal elasticity of substitution as the crucial parameter determining the curvature of the intertemporal utility function. In order to refer to aggregate data, the representative agent approach is adopted in most cases, analysing an economy as if it carries out an infinite horizon optimisation problem of a single, immortal, foresighted consumer. This approach requires a number of simplified assumptions about individual preferences.

Yet, the hypothesis of consumers monadically calculating their optimal consumption path far into the future by use of dynamic programming techniques and taking into account the probability distributions of future income streams, life-expectancy and real interest rates, is not just an ap-proach to consumption behaviour. It is one of the cornerstones of modern macroeconomics. As noted by Hahn & Solow (1997), post-Lucas macroeconomic theory stems from two essential commitments: first, a valid macroeconomic model should be the exact aggregation of a microeconomic model; second, the appropriate microeconomic model is based on intertemporal utility maximisation subject to budget constraints and technology only.

In fact, only extremely simplified models at the micro level allow for exact aggregation as the heterogeneity of agents has to be strictly curbed. Except for some recent developments in Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium modelling, heterogeneous agents have been entirely excluded in the dominant range of macroeconomic theory. We are not concerned with the consequences for the modelling of firms and competition here. Concerning the theory of the consumer, excluding heterogeneity requires a presumption of homothetic preferences; otherwise distributional parameters influence the aggregate outcome and devaluate the representative agent approach. Interdependencies and strategic interactions also have to be neglected. In fact, the standard LCPIH perfectly fulfils these needs and has therefore been used as an essential module of modern macroeconomic theory.

These models, impressive due to their sophisticated mathematical apparatus impeccably concealing bizarre underlying assumptions, are often the basis for straightforward policy advice. Lucas' critique of the Keynesian consumption function (Lucas, Sargent 1981) was in fact not so much targeted at theory than at policy. Indeed, if people do immediately calculate the permanent income value of a transitory income gain, any political attempt to stimulate demand during an economic downturn by, say, improved social benefits, is simply nonsense. Generally, if forward-looking consumers translate each piece of public debt into an expectation of an additional future tax burden, public deficit spending will only force private households to become particularly eager savers due to adjusted life-time consumption plans. If preferences are, moreover, homothetic, individual saving rates will be completely independent from permanent in-come. Under such conditions, suggesting a policy that favours low-income families in order to encourage effective demand is just an attestation of economic imbecility.

Therefore, the choice of which theory of saving is acceptable as a de-scription of real consumer behaviour and which should better be disre-garded, has far reaching consequences. Ultimately, this should lead to a scrutinising of the reality of the micro foundation of modern macroeco-nomics.

Erscheint lt. Verlag 2.10.2013
Zusatzinfo ca. 80 Grafiken und Tabellen, teils farbig
Verlagsort Frankfurt am Main
Sprache englisch
Themenwelt Sozialwissenschaften Politik / Verwaltung
Schlagworte Basic Needs • DDR • Deutschland • Einkommen • growth • Grundbedürfnis • Konsum • Makroökonomie • Real Income • saving • Saving Decisions • Sparen • Sparpolitik • Sparverhalten • USA • Volkswirtschaft • Wachstum
ISBN-10 3-593-42111-9 / 3593421119
ISBN-13 978-3-593-42111-7 / 9783593421117
Haben Sie eine Frage zum Produkt?
Wie bewerten Sie den Artikel?
Bitte geben Sie Ihre Bewertung ein:
Bitte geben Sie Daten ein:
PDFPDF (Wasserzeichen)
Größe: 2,7 MB

DRM: Digitales Wasserzeichen
Dieses eBook enthält ein digitales Wasser­zeichen und ist damit für Sie persona­lisiert. Bei einer missbräuch­lichen Weiter­gabe des eBooks an Dritte ist eine Rück­ver­folgung an die Quelle möglich.

Dateiformat: PDF (Portable Document Format)
Mit einem festen Seiten­layout eignet sich die PDF besonders für Fach­bücher mit Spalten, Tabellen und Abbild­ungen. Eine PDF kann auf fast allen Geräten ange­zeigt werden, ist aber für kleine Displays (Smart­phone, eReader) nur einge­schränkt geeignet.

Systemvoraussetzungen:
PC/Mac: Mit einem PC oder Mac können Sie dieses eBook lesen. Sie benötigen dafür einen PDF-Viewer - z.B. den Adobe Reader oder Adobe Digital Editions.
eReader: Dieses eBook kann mit (fast) allen eBook-Readern gelesen werden. Mit dem amazon-Kindle ist es aber nicht kompatibel.
Smartphone/Tablet: Egal ob Apple oder Android, dieses eBook können Sie lesen. Sie benötigen dafür einen PDF-Viewer - z.B. die kostenlose Adobe Digital Editions-App.

Zusätzliches Feature: Online Lesen
Dieses eBook können Sie zusätzlich zum Download auch online im Webbrowser lesen.

Buying eBooks from abroad
For tax law reasons we can sell eBooks just within Germany and Switzerland. Regrettably we cannot fulfill eBook-orders from other countries.

Mehr entdecken
aus dem Bereich
Mit „Green Growth“ gegen den Klimawandel und für die …

von Hans-Jörg Naumer

eBook Download (2023)
Springer Fachmedien Wiesbaden (Verlag)
9,99