Can We Avoid Another Financial Crisis? (eBook)

(Autor)

eBook Download: EPUB
2017
John Wiley & Sons (Verlag)
978-1-5095-1376-5 (ISBN)

Lese- und Medienproben

Can We Avoid Another Financial Crisis? - Steve Keen
Systemvoraussetzungen
16,99 inkl. MwSt
  • Download sofort lieferbar
  • Zahlungsarten anzeigen

The Great Financial Crash had cataclysmic effects on the global economy, and took conventional economists completely by surprise. Many leading commentators declared shortly before the crisis that the magical recipe for eternal stability had been found. Less than a year later, the biggest economic crisis since the Great Depression erupted.
In this explosive book, Steve Keen, one of the very few economists who anticipated the crash, shows why the self-declared experts were wrong and how ever-rising levels of private debt make another financial crisis almost inevitable unless politicians tackle the real dynamics causing financial instability. He also identifies the economies that have become 'The Walking Dead of Debt', and those that are next in line - including Australia, Belgium, China, Canada and South Korea.
A major intervention by a fearlessly iconoclastic figure, this book is essential reading for anyone who wants to understand the true nature of the global economic system.



Steve Keen is Professor of Economics and Head of the School of Economics, Politics and History at Kingston University.
The Great Financial Crash had cataclysmic effects on the global economy, and took conventional economists completely by surprise. Many leading commentators declared shortly before the crisis that the magical recipe for eternal stability had been found. Less than a year later, the biggest economic crisis since the Great Depression erupted. In this explosive book, Steve Keen, one of the very few economists who anticipated the crash, shows why the self-declared experts were wrong and how ever rising levels of private debt make another financial crisis almost inevitable unless politicians tackle the real dynamics causing financial instability. He also identifies the economies that have become 'The Walking Dead of Debt', and those that are next in line including Australia, Belgium, China, Canada and South Korea. A major intervention by a fearlessly iconoclastic figure, this book is essential reading for anyone who wants to understand the true nature of the global economic system.

Steve Keen is Professor of Economics and Head of the School of Economics, Politics and History at Kingston University.

Acknowledgements

List of Tables and Figures

1. From Triumph to Crisis in Economics

2. Microeconomics, Macroeconomics and Complexity

3. The Lull and The Storm

4. The Smoking Gun of Credit

5. The Political Economy of Private Debt

6. A Cynic?s Conclusion

Endnotes

Bibliography

"No one is more qualified than Steve Keen to answer the question "Can we avoid another financial crisis?" with more than a single word. Read this book!"
--Yanis Varoufakis, former Finance Minister of Greece

"In this compelling essay, Steve Keen shows that the "Great Moderation" was in fact a great delusion and documents, to brutal effect, the foolish complacency of mainstream macroeconomists."
--James K. Galbraith, University of Texas at Austin

"Steve Keen explains why the financial crisis it occurred, and why it can't just get better on its own, along its present track. He also explains - in a hilarious and absolutely justified takedown - why mainstream economists have a "trained incapacity" in being unable to understand why the economy has broken down - and hence, why they don't have a real solution. We are still living in the aftermath of the 2008 crisis. It's all about debt. But economists fear they will lose their jobs if they say that debts must be written down. Keen asks what is more important: to save the economy, or to save the jobs for economists whose prestige rests on their not understanding why economies are in trouble today."
--Michael Hudson, author of Killing the Host and The Bubble and Beyond

"Non-academics interested in economic or financial markets should, if they read ony one book on the topic, absolutely read this one."
--International Investment

"Mr. Keen is surely right to argue that growth fuelled by the continuing expansion of private debt is highly risky for the overall economy, and that which cannot continue indefinitely will come to a sticky end sooner rather than later. We should heed his advice..."
--Globe and Mail

1
From Triumph to Crisis in Economics


There was a time when the question this book poses would have generated derisory guffaws from leading economists – and that time was not all that long ago. In December 2003, the Nobel Prize winner Robert Lucas began his Presidential Address to the American Economic Association with the triumphant claim that economic crises like the Great Depression were now impossible:

Macroeconomics was born as a distinct field in the 1940s, as a part of the intellectual response to the Great Depression. The term then referred to the body of knowledge and expertise that we hoped would prevent the recurrence of that economic disaster. My thesis in this lecture is that macroeconomics in this original sense has succeeded: Its central problem of depression prevention has been solved, for all practical purposes, and has in fact been solved for many decades. (Lucas, 2003, p. 1, emphasis added)

Four years later, that claim fell apart, as first the USA and then the global economy entered the deepest and longest crisis since the Great Depression. Almost a decade later, the recovery from that crisis is fragile at best. The question of whether another financial crisis may occur can no longer be glibly dismissed.

That question was first posed decades earlier by the then unknown but now famous maverick American economist Hyman Minsky. Writing two decades before Lucas, Minsky remarked that ‘The most significant economic event of the era since World War II is something that has not happened: there has not been a deep and long-lasting depression’ (1982, p. ix).1 In contrast, before the Second World War, ‘serious recessions happened regularly . . . to go more than thirty-five years without a severe and protracted depression is a striking success’. To Minsky, this meant that the most important questions in economics were:

Can ‘It’ – a Great Depression – happen again? And if ‘It’ can happen, why didn’t ‘It’ occur in the years since World War II? These are questions that naturally follow from both the historical record and the comparative success of the past thirty-five years. (1982, p. xii)

Minsky’s ultimate conclusion was that crises in pure free-market capitalism were inevitable, because thanks to its financial system, capitalism ‘is inherently flawed, being prone to booms, crises, and depressions:

This instability, in my view, is due to characteristics the financial system must possess if it is to be consistent with full-blown capitalism. Such a financial system will be capable of both generating signals that induce an accelerating desire to invest and of financing that accelerating investment. (Minsky, 1969, p. 224)

A serious crisis hadn’t occurred since the Second World War, Minsky argued, because the post-war economy was not a pure free-market system, but rather was a mixed market–state economy where the state was five times larger than it was before the Great Depression. A crisis had been prevented because spending by ‘Big Government’ during recessions had prevented ‘the collapse of profits which is a necessary condition for a deep and long depression’ (Minsky, 1982, p. xiii).

Given that Minsky reached this conclusion in 1982, and that Lucas’s claim that the problem ‘of depression prevention has been solved . . . for many decades’ occurred in 2003, you might think that Lucas, like Minsky, thought that ‘Big Government’ prevented depressions, and that this belief was proven false by the 2008 crisis.

If only it were that simple. In fact, Lucas had reached precisely the opposite opinions about the stability of capitalism and the desirable policy to Minsky, because the question that preoccupied him was not Minsky’s ‘Can “It” – a Great Depression – happen again?’, but the rather more esoteric question ‘Can we derive macroeconomic theory from microeconomics?’

Ever since Keynes wrote The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money (1936), economists have divided their discipline into two components: ‘microeconomics’, which considers the behaviour of consumers and firms; and ‘macroeconomics’, which considers the behaviour of the economy as a whole. Microeconomics has always been based on a model of consumers who aimed to maximise their utility, firms that aimed to maximise their profits, and a market system that achieved equilibrium between these two forces by equating supply and demand in every market. Macroeconomics before Lucas, on the other hand, was based on a mathematical interpreta-tion of Keynes’s attempt to explain why the Great Depression occurred, which was developed not by Keynes but by his contemporary John Hicks.

Though Hicks himself regarded his IS-LM model (‘Investment-Savings & Liquidity-Money’) as compatible with microeconomic theory (Hicks, 1981, p. 153; 1937, pp. 141–2), Lucas did not, because the model implied that government spending could boost aggregate demand during recessions. This was inconsistent with standard microeconomics, which argued that markets work best in the absence of government interventions.

Starting in the late 1960s, Lucas and his colleagues developed an approach to macroeconomics which was derived directly from standard microeconomic theory, which they called ‘New Classical Macroeconomics’. In contrast to the IS-LM model, it asserted that, if consumers and firms were rational – which Lucas and his disciples interpreted to mean (a) that consumers and firms modelled the future impact of government policies using the economic theory that Lucas and his colleagues had developed, and (b) that this theory accurately predicted the consequences of those policies – then the government would be unable to alter aggregate demand because, whatever it did, the public would do the opposite:

there is no sense in which the authority has the option to conduct countercyclical policy . . . by virtue of the assumption that expectations are rational, there is no feedback rule that the authority can employ and expect to be able systematically to fool the public. (Sargent & Wallace, 1976, pp. 177–8)

Over the next few decades, this vision of a microfounded macroeconomics in which the government was largely impotent led to the development of complicated mathematical models of the economy, which became known as ‘Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium’ (DSGE) models.

This intellectual process was neither peaceful nor apolitical. The first models, known as ‘Real Business Cycle’ (RBC) models, assumed that all markets worked perfectly, and asserted that all unemployment was voluntary – including the 25 per cent unemployment rates of the Great Depression (Prescott, 1999; Cole & Ohanian, 2004). This was too much for many economists, and what is now known as the ‘Freshwater–Saltwater’ divide developed within the mainstream of the profession.

The more politically progressive ‘Saltwater’ economists (who described themselves as ‘New Keynesians’) took the RBC models developed by their ‘Freshwater’ rivals and added in ‘market imperfections’ – which were also derived from standard microeconomic theory – to generate DSGE models. The market imperfections built into these models meant that if the model economy were disturbed from equilibrium by a ‘shock’, ‘frictions’ due to those imperfections would slow down the return to equilibrium, resulting in both slower growth and involuntary unemployment.

These ‘New Keynesian’ DSGE models came to dominate macroeconomic theory and policy around the world, and by 2007 they were the workhorse models of Treasuries and Central Banks. A representative (and, at the time, very highly regarded) DSGE model of the US economy had two types of firms (final goods producers operating in a ‘perfect’ market, and intermediate goods producers operating in an ‘imperfect’ one); one type of household (a worker–capitalist–bond trader amalgam that supplied labour via a trade union, earnt dividends from the two types of firms, and received interest income from government bonds); a trade union setting wages; and a government sector consisting of a revenue-constrained, bond-issuing fiscal authority and an activist Central Bank, which varied the interest rate in response to deviations of inflation and GDP growth from its target (Smets & Wouters, 2007).

Notably, a government that could affect employment by fiscal policy was normally absent from DSGE models, as was a financial sector – and indeed money itself. The mindset that developed within the economics profession – and especially within Central Banks – was that these factors could be ignored in macroeconomics. Instead, if the Central Bank used DSGE models to guide policy, and therefore set the interest rate properly, economic growth and inflation would both reach desirable levels, and the economy would reach a Nirvana state of full employment and low inflation.

Right up until mid-2007, this model of the economy seemed to accurately describe the real world. Unemployment, which had peaked at 11 per cent in the USA in the 1983 recession, peaked at under 8 per cent in the early 1990s recession...

Erscheint lt. Verlag 9.5.2017
Reihe/Serie Blackwell Companions to History
Blackwell Companions to History
The Future of Capitalism
Sprache englisch
Themenwelt Sozialwissenschaften Politik / Verwaltung Staat / Verwaltung
Wirtschaft Volkswirtschaftslehre Finanzwissenschaft
Wirtschaft Volkswirtschaftslehre Wirtschaftspolitik
Schlagworte Business & Management • Business & Society • debt, political economy, financial crisis, financial crash, private debt, economics, Steve Keen, debunking, debunking economics, political economics. • Economics • Finanzkrise • political economics • Politische Ökonomie • Volkswirtschaftslehre • Wirtschaft u. Gesellschaft • Wirtschaft u. Management
ISBN-10 1-5095-1376-0 / 1509513760
ISBN-13 978-1-5095-1376-5 / 9781509513765
Informationen gemäß Produktsicherheitsverordnung (GPSR)
Haben Sie eine Frage zum Produkt?
EPUBEPUB (Adobe DRM)
Größe: 1,3 MB

Kopierschutz: Adobe-DRM
Adobe-DRM ist ein Kopierschutz, der das eBook vor Mißbrauch schützen soll. Dabei wird das eBook bereits beim Download auf Ihre persönliche Adobe-ID autorisiert. Lesen können Sie das eBook dann nur auf den Geräten, welche ebenfalls auf Ihre Adobe-ID registriert sind.
Details zum Adobe-DRM

Dateiformat: EPUB (Electronic Publication)
EPUB ist ein offener Standard für eBooks und eignet sich besonders zur Darstellung von Belle­tristik und Sach­büchern. Der Fließ­text wird dynamisch an die Display- und Schrift­größe ange­passt. Auch für mobile Lese­geräte ist EPUB daher gut geeignet.

Systemvoraussetzungen:
PC/Mac: Mit einem PC oder Mac können Sie dieses eBook lesen. Sie benötigen eine Adobe-ID und die Software Adobe Digital Editions (kostenlos). Von der Benutzung der OverDrive Media Console raten wir Ihnen ab. Erfahrungsgemäß treten hier gehäuft Probleme mit dem Adobe DRM auf.
eReader: Dieses eBook kann mit (fast) allen eBook-Readern gelesen werden. Mit dem amazon-Kindle ist es aber nicht kompatibel.
Smartphone/Tablet: Egal ob Apple oder Android, dieses eBook können Sie lesen. Sie benötigen eine Adobe-ID sowie eine kostenlose App.
Geräteliste und zusätzliche Hinweise

Buying eBooks from abroad
For tax law reasons we can sell eBooks just within Germany and Switzerland. Regrettably we cannot fulfill eBook-orders from other countries.

Mehr entdecken
aus dem Bereich
Für ein prinzipientreues und rechtsstaatliches Steuerrecht

von Reiner Sahm

eBook Download (2024)
Springer Gabler (Verlag)
37,99